Tuesday, May 10, 2011

Fewer Drugs, Shorter Lives, Less Prosperity: The Impact Of Comparative Effectiveness Research on Health and Wealth

Editor's Note: This is an important piece on Comparative Effectiveness Research from the Center for Medicine in the Public Interest, a leading voice in the struggle to improve our national health through the expansion of personal freedom and the advancement of Serious Medicine.



Fewer Drugs, Shorter Lives, Less Prosperity: 
The Impact Of 
Comparative Effectiveness Research 
on Health and Wealth

by 

John Vernon, Ph. D.
Robert Goldberg Ph. D.
Peter Pitts


Executive Summary

1. Advocates of comparative effectiveness research (“CER”) claim it can be used to reduce healthcare spending because a large portion pays for medical technologies that add little health or social benefit. This assumption runs counter to evidence that medical innovation is associated with lower and greater longevity

2. To the extent that CER is used to reduce the development and use of new drugs, devices, and diagnostics, it is important to estimate what impact the reduced rate of innovation would have on quality of life and life expectancy.

3. Using empirical models that establish a direct relationship between pharmaceutical returns on investment and clinical development costs, we developed an estimate of the cost of CER and it’s impact on rates of research and development (“R&D”).

4. We found that CER could conservatively increase R&D costs by an amount equally to 50 percent of the most complex and time-consuming part of drug development. The added cost would reduce R&D spending by $32 billion over ten years.

5. Based on research that quantified the relationship between increased R&D and greater life expectancy and well being, we conclude that CER would cost Americans 81 million life years and $4 trillion dollars.

6. CER advocates ignore the impact of such requirements at the possible expense of longer life and economic growth.

Introduction

Many observers maintain that the increase in healthcare spending is the result of the development and overuse of new medicines, devices, and diagnostics. In arguing this case, proponents of this view three assumptions. First, that most of the ‘overuse’ does not improve health or extend life. Second, that CER information about the costs, risks, and benefits of different treatment options, combined with new incentives reflecting the information, could eventually alter the way in which medicine is practiced and yield lower healthcare spending without having adverse effects on health. Over the long-term, the potential reduction in spending below projected levels could be substantial. Third, CER can be used so “that Medicare spending—and perhaps all health spending in the country—could be cut by about 30 percent if the more conservative practice styles used in the lowest spending one-fifth of the country could be adopted nationwide.”(1)

Based on these assumptions the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act both requires the development of CER and its use in defining healthcare quality and in making coverage decisions. Some of the strongest proponents and contributors to the body of CER “as Congress moves toward substantial reductions in Medicare spending, the program will be under increasing pressure to ensure that dollars are directed to services providing known benefits.” Dr. Donald Berwick, who is administrator of the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services, put the case for CER more bluntly: “We can make a sensible social decision and say, ‘Well, at this point, we have access to a particular additional benefit [new drug or medical intervention] is so expensive that our taxpayers have better use for those funds.’”(2)  Indeed, the Institute of Medicine charged with developing methods for determining what technologies and innovations should be part of and added to the package of benefits covered under the new health care law. CER will be the major tool for making such determinations.(3)

If these assumptions were true, medical innovation overtime should have led to both a significant increase in spending and almost no result in the worst of both worlds – a large increase in cost and little or no increase in well being and life expectancy with improved quality of life. Previous studies have cast doubt on such assertions. Indeed, a rich body of empirical research demonstrates “that medical innovation has yielded significant increases in life expectancy without increasing medical expenditure.” Frank Lichtenberg has shown that the pace and intensity of medical innovation is associated with lower growth in per capita medical expenditures, longer life and economic growth.

Yale University's William Nordhaus has estimated the value of innovations in medicine during the second half of the twentieth century to be roughly equal to the gains in the economy’s real output, as measured by the Gross Domestic Product (“GDP”) over  the same fifty-year period. The value of improvements in health (e.g. life expectancy) unlike the economy’s real productive output of goods and services is not reflected in national accounting statistics (which when aggregated, measure economic growth and national income, i.e GDP).

Nordhaus posits a simple, and indeed, quite clever question to demonstrate the intuitive reasonableness of his conclusion, which is based on highly technical research methods:

You must forgo either the health improvements over the last half-century or the non-health improvements. That is, you must choose either (a) 1950 health conditions and 2000 non-health living standards or (b) 2000 health conditions and 1950 non-health living standards. Which would you choose?(4)

In another study, one that was prospective rather than retrospective, University of Chicago Economists, Kevin Murphy and Robert Topel, estimated the social-economic value of a 10 percent reduction in the mortality associated with cardiovascular disease and cancer around $10 trillion (roughly $4 trillion from reductions in cardiovascular  mortality and $6 trillion from reductions in cancer mortality). To place this number in perspective, note that the size of the U.S. economy, as measured by the GDP, surpassed the $10 trillion level a few years ago in the early 2000’s.

The productivity of investment in pharmaceutical R&D is remarkably high—perhaps one of the most productive uses of capital in the economy. Hence, our research looked at whether incentives to either maintain or increase investment in R&D would be affected by the need to conduct CER prior to and a condition for coverage of a new medicine.

En route to engaging in this research, we looked at the impact of the introduction of cholesterol lowering drugs called statins on the death rate from heart disease. Advocates of CER argue that requiring its development and use can produce better health at a lower cost. Or, to use the language of the Nordhaus Paradox, CER can lead to better health and (because it would save money) improved non-health living standards.

As Table 1 shows, the development of statins is associated with a significant decline in 10-year death rates among men and women regardless of whether or not they have a history of heart disease. CER proponents would argue that CER could produce similar gains at a lower per patient cost.


The Impact of CER on Medical Innovation

Yet, CER is not generated overnight or at little cost to companies whose products are to be compared. Rather, as with any requirement for additional evidence, there are both direct and indirect costs associated with its production. (This is a point that CER advocates often make when justifying the establishment of a government agency that would set the CER agenda as well as subsidize CER projects.)

In previous research, we have demonstrated how CER regulations have the potential to result in increasing clinical trial sizes (and costs) and perhaps clinical development times; the latter would increase the cost and risk of drug development from an investment, decision-making perspective.(5)

The mathematics of clinical research are the same whether an innovator needs to provide more clinical data before or as a condition of receiving Food and Drug Administration (“FDA”) approval or CER data before or as a condition to being coverage by health plans or government. Either way, requirement for more information will require companies to increase the size of clinical trial samples. CER can increase the complexity of clinical trials, the number of people enrolled in a clinical trial, and the number of studies conducted after a product receives approval. In Europe, “about one-fourth to one-third of the regulatory costs are estimated to go for reimbursement issues.

Further, CER can delay time to market and reduce the rate and extent of technology diffusion. A recent study looking at the impact of CER on market access in Europe and the United States, found the process delayed use by over two years. Moreover, the same study found that CER use, as part of reimbursement decisions in cancer was associated with 60 percent fewer medications being made available than when such reviews were not used.(6)

CER also adds to the risk of investing because it increases the uncertainty about whether a product will enter the market. The uncertainty ranges “from the impossibility of demonstrating the full scope of a product’s value at the time of authorization, through to the impossibility of knowing precisely what will be on the market (and how good it is compared to your product) by the time you get to seeking authorization. As research departments and company finance offers have frequently lamented, there is a profound discouragement to innovation when every new product runs the risk of flat rejection by
regulators at the last minute, because of some unforeseeable arrival of another, arguably superior, therapy just before you seek authorization.”(7)

Unless CER costs nothing, it will make more developmental R&D projects less attractive. That is, with higher expected drug or device development costs, slower access to market and increased uncertainty, there will be fewer R&D projects with generating positive returns (particularly cash flows). Figure 1 shows that as the cost of conducting CER increase the number of R&D projects decline in order to maintain the same rate of return on innovation.


Next, we estimated how much the R&D investment would decline or be “lost” due to an increase in CER costs. We assume that CER would be 50 percent of Phase III clinical development costs. This estimate is based on empirical data of development costs and the recognition that the complexity of clinical trials and number of patients required to do comparative research would increase throughout the FDA evaluation stage.

As Table 2 shows, over a 10-year period, R&D investment would decline by $31.6 billion. Over the long term, R&D would increase but at slower rate due to CER.


CER Impact on Life Expectancy and Dollars

As we discussed earlier, the investment in and consumption of new medicines continually increases life expectancy, quality of life, and productivity. To estimate the social impact of CER, we estimate how much lost R&D will cost Americans in terms of lower life expectancy and dollars. To translate life years into dollars, we use the conservative assumption that a life year is equal to $50,000. While much higher estimates exist, we are opting to be conservative in all of our assumptions so that our estimates may plausibly be viewed as lower-bound approximations. Table 3 shows that the R&D lost due to CER will cost the United States 81 million life years and $4 trillion over 20 years.


Conclusion

Proponents of CER have responded to general criticism of using findings to make coverage decisions by claiming that absent such research, the United States will be unable to control rising health costs because of the unfettered adoption of medical innovations. Some have gone so far as to suggest that “the antagonism toward cost-per-quality adjusted life year comparisons also suggests a bit of magical thinking — the notion that the country can avoid the difficult trade-offs that cost-utility analysis helps to illuminate … It represents another example of our country’s avoidance of unpleasant truths about our resource constraints.”(8)

Our research shows that there is hard evidence behind our concern about using CER to “illuminate” difficult tradeoffs. On the contrary, our analysis suggests that because CER will lead to a loss of innovation, Americans will live shorter lives, and in poorer health than would otherwise be the case. Simply put, we will produce less health. People will be less productive and less able to enjoy life. Living longer will be worthless. (Since people who are in poor health cost more to care for than healthy people even if they live longer, CER will also add to healthcare spending.) That is the "unpleasant truth" CER advocates consistently avoid.



###

Footnotes

1) CBO Research on the Comparative Effectiveness of Medical Treatments: Issues and Options for an Expanded Federal Role, December 2007.

2) Donald Berwick, June 2009 interview in Biotechnology Healthcare.

3)  http://iom.edu/Activities/HealthServices/EssentialHealthBenefits/2011-JAN-12/Agenda.aspx

4) William Nordhaus. “Irving Fisher and the Contribution of Improved Longevity to Living Standards” The American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64(1): 367-92. 2005.

5) Vernon JA, Goldberg R, and Golec J. Economic evaluation and cost effectiveness thresholds: signals to firms and implications for R&D investment and innovation. Pharmacoeconomics 2009; 27 (10): 797-806.

6) Anne Mason, et al., “Comparison of Anti-cancer Drug Coverage Decisions in the United States and United Kingdom: Does the Evidence Support the Rhetoric?” Journal of Clinical Oncology, http://
jco.ascopubs.org/content/28/20/3234.abstract.

7)  Peter O’Donnell, “One Step Closer to the Fourth Hurdle: Drug Evaluation Criteria Could Soon Include an Intrusive Health Technology Assessment.” Applied Clinical Trials, March 1 2010.

8) Jonathan Skinner, NEJM.

^^^

About the Authors

John A. Vernon, PhD

Dr. Vernon is a professor in the Department of Health Policy and Administration at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, where he holds appointments in the Kenan-Flagler School of Business and the UNC School of Pharmacy. He is a Faculty Research Fellow with the National Bureau of Economic Research and a Senior Economic Policy Advisor to the Office of the Commissioner at the US FDA.

He has twice testified before the US Senate on pharmaceutical policy issues and advises both government and industry on a wide range of policy issues. He was previously a professor in the finance department at the University of Connecticut and a visiting professor at the Wharton School of Business at the University of Pennsylvania. He also guest edited a special issue of Managerial and Decision Economics on the political economy of the pharmaceutical industry.

Dr. Vernon has published articles in numerous publications, including The Journal of Law and Economics, Health Economics, Healthcare Management, The Journal of Healthcare Management, The National Law Journal, The American Journal of Law and Medicine, and PharmacoEconomics, where he sits on the editorial board.

Dr. Vernon holds doctoral degrees from the University of Pennsylvania's Wharton School in management science (health policy and management) and the University of London in economics.

Robert M. Goldberg, PhD

Robert Goldberg is co-founder and vice president of the Center for Medicine in the Public Interest. (CMPI) Along with Peter Pitts, Dr. Goldberg hosts the popular and controversial blog on the pharmaceutical industry and healthcare, www.drugwonks.com.

Prior to founding CMPI, Goldberg was Director of the Manhattan Institute’s Center for Medical Progress and Chairman of its 21st Century FDA Task Force that examined the impact of the FDA’s Critical Path Initiative on drug development and personalized medicine.

He has written for The Wall Street Journal, The Washington Post, The Los Angeles Times, National Review Online, The Chicago Tribune, The Philadelphia InquirerThe New York Sun and writes regularly for The American Spectator, where he broke the story about Obama Medicare director Donald Berwick’s admiration for Britain’s National Health Service; The New York Post and The Weekly Standard. He is an expert on Medicare reform, comparative effectiveness and FDA’s Critical Path Initiative and the author of many papers including, "Insta-Americans: The Empowered (and Imperiled) Health Care Consumer in the Age of Internet Medicine," and with John Vernon, "Alzheimer's Disease and Cost-effectiveness Analyses: Ensuring Good Value for Money?" and “Economic Evaluation and Comparative-Effectiveness Thresholds: Signals to Firms and Implications for R&D Investment and Innovation.” He is also author of Tabloid Medicine: How the Internet is Being Used To Hijack Medical Science For Fear and Profit. (Kaplan, December 2010).

Peter Pitts

Peter Pitts is President and co-founder of the Center for Medicine in the Public Interest and Partner/Director Global Healthcare, Porter Novelli. Prior to founding CMPI, Pitts was a Senior Fellow for healthcare studies at the Pacific Research Institute. From 2002-2004 Peter was FDA’s Associate Commissioner for External Relations,  serving as senior communications and policy adviser to the Commissioner. He supervised FDA's Office of Public Affairs, Office of the Ombudsman, Office of Special Health Issues, Office of Executive Secretariat, and Advisory Committee Oversight and
Management. He served on the agency’s obesity working group and counterfeit drug taskforce.

His book, Become Strategic or Die, is widely recognized as a cutting edge study of how leadership, in order to be successful over the long term, must be combined with strategic vision and ethical practice. He is the editor of the new book, Coincidence or Crisis, which deals with the public health crisis of counterfeit medicines. He has served as an adjunct professor at Indiana University’s School of Public and Environmental Affairs and Butler University.

About CMPI

The Center for Medicine in the Public Interest is a nonprofit, non-partisan organization promoting innovative solutions that advance medical progress, reduce health disparities, extend life and make health care more affordable, preventive and patient-centered. CMPI also provides the public, policymakers and the media a reliable source of independent scientific analysis on issues ranging from personalized medicine, food and drug safety, health care reform and comparative effectiveness.  CMPI can be found at  www.cmpi.org and www.drugwonks.com.




4 comments:

  1. WHAT SHOULD HAPPEN

    Congress and the White House should stop wasting the people’s money. There are many ways to “cut as detailed herein” and use savings to improve quality of basic invested entitlements. Congress should transition to an improved Medicare. Vote opponents to this “out”. Citizens come first.
    It is time the U.S. reduces human rites and police activities for the World by lobbying the United Nations, NATO and Interpol to “take on more”. 800 bases in 63 countries across the world should be reduced. Examples are fewer forces in, Bosnia, Germany, Philippines and Okinawa.
    Starting with Iraq, only train for self reliance. After the surge in Afghanistan train and diminish corruption by requiring accounting practices for aid, substituting minerals mining and food crops for drugs. Its time for both to pay for military supplies and consulting.
    Cut bloated federal bureaucracy and expenses. Combine CDC, EPA and FDA. Combine the FAA, NHTSA and DOT. Combine GAO and CBO. Eliminate “must spend all”. Return “unused” yearly budget to the treasury. Cut budgets (other than entitlements) on an average of 10%. Implement GAO’s report to Congress on eliminating duplication, overlap and fragmentation in 81 of the federal government’s departmets, agencies, programs, offices and initiatives.
    Eliminate all 32 czars Mr. President. Reduce your 469 member staff which makes nearly 39 million per year! Halt first lady $180,000 air force one vacation trips. Stop “multi million dollars per day” presidential-family foreign trips.
    Contribute to only one of: The World Bank or International Monetary Fund or U.S. Agency for International Development.
    Reduce foreign aid bribery. For example, no aid to oil rich -Iraq. $37 billion and increasing with $8.7 billion of development funds not accounted for. Halt $150 million aid to Palestinians. Slash $1.3 billion annually to Egypt and Pakistan!
    Charge bailed companies (TARP) for their huge executive bonuses at taxpayer expense. Government should sell shares to recoup for taxpayer. Billions still owed?
    Congress should reduce “stimulus” expenditures by halting over budget and vote bribery “earmarks”. Example: Stop “cow burp” study. Take back $13 billion unspent in states. Eliminate subsidies that smell “earmark”. Congress should cut its pay and do not pay student loans for their staff or family from their operating budgets. Please- no renting of private or military aircraft. An example was Pelosi’s family of $2.1 million for over 2 years. Congress should set commercial travel cost standards and controls.
    Reduce medical cost by: allowing purchasing in any state, “tort reform”, and reducing “red tape”. Reduce Medicare fraud by expediting billing cost speed, and doctor/patient screening of state controlled local provider groups.
    Congress should enforce existing immigration laws and implement “no illegal birthrights”. Entitlements or benefits should be for only citizens. Deport criminal “illegals”. Only deportees and workers on Visa/Guest Programs qualify for needed medical benefits. Complete an improved fence. 56% of this border is uncontrolled.
    Corporations should be allowed tax reduction incentives for hiring with healthcare plan options.
    These actions will improve funding for:” Medicare”, “Medicaid, and “Veteran’s Affairs”.
    Healthcare quality can be at least that for Congress or the Federal Employee Health Benefits Program (FEHBP). Additional benefits are: dental coverage, improved visual coverage, no drug “donut hole”, no pre-existing conditions, and no deductibles and co-pays except for extended skilled level nursing.
    Other benefits are aid for unemployment compensation and Social Security with reinstated cost of living increases.

    ReplyDelete
  2. That's why its more practical that you may appropriate study previous to developing. You'll be able to post more significant posting like this. Buy weed online

    ReplyDelete
  3. You there, this is really good post here. Thanks for taking the time to post such valuable information. Quality content is what always gets the visitors coming. albino penis envy trip

    ReplyDelete